Debate: Ukraine's Future Governance
Semi-Presidentialism, Political Reform, and the Future of Ukrainian Democracy
by Andreas Umland
Source: Foreign Policy Journal.
The current public controversy about what division of power Ukraine should have in the future
is overdue.
The various political crises of the past fifteen years have
amply shown that the Ukrainian Constitution, whether in its 1996 or
2004 versions, needs revision. However, the arguments made in
Ukrainian mass media today concerning constitutional reform mostly
ignore what political science has to say about the appropriateness of
various forms of presidential rule for post-communist transition states.
For this reason, many of the current public exchanges about the
division of power that Ukraine supposedly requires miss the point. These
discussions are mainly about the amount of prerogatives that Ukraine’s
future more or less powerful
President should have. The arguments thus remain within the realm of a
comparison between the “Kuchmism” of 1996-2004, and the dual rule of
2006-2010 – neither very successful periods in recent Ukrainian
political history. Sometimes, Ukraine’s semi-presidential
proto-democratic system is even compared to Russia’s pseudo-presidential
authoritarian regime.
Comparative
political research suggests that, instead, the country needs a serious
discussion about of the range and structure of the prerogatives of parliament.
Ideally, such a revision of the Ukrainian Constitution would lead to
the establishment of a political system dominated by the Verkhovna Rada,
and with a weak President. Or it would mean the creation of a de jure
parliamentary republic with a non-elected figurehead President. At
least, this is what the results of recent investigations by political
scientists into the political systems in the post-communist space
prescribe.
Most of the deliberations concerning a modification of the Constitution currently shown on Ukrainian TV channels
are about whether Ukraine should have a presidential-parliamentary or
parliamentary-presidential form of government. These are two versions of
the semi-presidential form of government — the necessity of which is
taken for granted by many, if not most discussants. The first
presidential-parliamentary version refers, in the Ukrainian case, to the
original regulations of the 1996 Constitution of Ukraine. It implies
an, in fact, super-presidential system where the Prime-Minister is
reduced to the role of an assistant to, scapegoat for, and whipping boy
of the President. The second, parliamentary-presidential version,
instead, refers to the real division of government that has come into
force on January 1st, 2006. Since then, the Ukrainian state’s executive
prerogatives have been divided between President and Prime-Minister.
Arguably, only since 2006 has the term “semi-presidentialism” actually
come to make sense in describing Ukraine’s political system. Before
that, the substantive powers of the President where closer to a purely
and strongly presidential system of government rather than reminiscent
of a divided executive like that of contemporary France.
The
problem with the hotly discussed pros and cons of both systems is that
this controversy is largely oblivious to what specialists on
semi-presidentialism in Eastern Europe and the post-Soviet space have
been publishing in recent years. In a way, this situation reflects the
general absence of political science in most of Ukraine’s political debates.
Instead, these controversies often prominently feature politicians,
“political technologists,” and journalists who are, for different
reasons, ill-prepared to contribute constructive arguments to such debates.
Many politicians assume (sometimes quite wrongly so) that this or that
constitutional arrangement is or will be better for them than others.
While even self-serving politicians may thus occasionally pronounce a
valid argument, they do so for the wrong reason. The same goes for most
of the politically engaged pundits who dominate Ukrainian mass media and
are paid not to provide detached analysis, but to engage in
pseudo-analytic public lobbying in the (occasionally also misunderstood)
interests of their sponsors.
Many journalists commenting on
semi-presidentialism, in turn, may do so with good intentions,
but have little expertise or even limited interest in the specifics of
comparative political science, empirical social research, or democratic
constitutional engineering. Occasionally, such debates even involve
artists, novelists, and other intellectuals, who are willing to say
something on current Ukrainian affairs, but, in doing so, go far beyond
their professional competence. The extensive involvement of dilettantes
in such debates seems to be a direct result of the dearth of serious
political scientists within the public sphere. The latter, in turn, is
an obvious repercussion of the virtual absence of political science in
Ukraine until 1991, and the field’s relative underdevelopment, in the
entire post-Soviet space, until today.
The
current Ukrainian controversy can be compared to a hypothetical
community discussion about a new bridge, where the construction of the
future viaduct is based on opinions from those drivers, pedestrians, and
fishermen who will later use that bridge, on a daily basis. To involve
architects and engineers in the planning of such a bridge is seen as a
waste of time. Such building experts will constitute only a miniscule
portion of the people who will later actually use the bridge. Moreover,
construction engineers may come up with difficult concepts, complicated mathematics,
and intricate opinions. Non-specialists may find their assertions
incomprehensible, tiresome, and pretentious. Arguably, bridges should be
constructed by those who actually will depend on them, and not by aloof
experts who have no inner relation to, and patriotic feelings on, the
object to be build. Approximately, such a line of thinking seems to be
responsible for the current absence of specialists on comparative
politics and constitutional engineering in Ukrainian debates over
governmental reform. That is even more surprising in view of the fact
that the reconstruction of Ukraine’s basic law can be seen as a task far
more consequential and complicated task than building a bridge.
Two
major recent studies of democracy in East-Central Europe and the former
Soviet Union have, independently from each other and based on different
methodologies, come to largely similar inferences concerning the
question: Which political regimes are most conducive to sustainable
democratization in post-communist transition states? In 2006, Steven
Fish presented a seminal paper based on quantitative comparative
analysis and tellingly called “Strong Legislatures, Stronger
Democracies” in the influential Journal of Democracy (vol. 17,
no. 1) published by the National Endowment for Democracy. In 2008,
Robert Elgie and Sophia Moestrup published the collected volume Semi-Presidentialism in Central and Eastern Europe under the imprint of Manchester University
Press. The conclusions by Fish, Elgie and Moestrup provide somewhat
distinct, but equally clear criteria for an assessment of the effects on
democratization of the various semi-presidential systems that Ukraine
has had since 1991.
The two equally
comprehensive accounts of various divisions of power come to similar
conclusions concerning the chances for a success of democratization:
both presidential-parliamentary and parliamentary-presidential systems
are problematic for young post-communist proto-democracies. Summarizing
the results of their qualitative multi-author study of twelve Central
and East European states, Elgie and Moestrup find that especially those
varieties of semi-presidentialism where the president’s prerogatives are
moderately or very extensive create more problems than they solve.
Only, semi-presidential regimes with a relatively weak, yet still
popularly elected president have had no significant harmful consequences
for democracy. Elgie and Moestrup conclude:
[M]ore
often than not [semi-presidentialism's] effect was somewhat negative,
or at least unhelpful to the democratization process…. The unhelpful
impact of semi-presidentialism was particularly clear in the case of
highly presidentialized semi-presidentialism [like Ukraine had until
December 2005 - A.U.] and the balanced presidential-prime ministerial
semi-presidentialism [like Ukraine has had since January 2006 - A.U.].
At
the end of their book, the two experts therefore advise policy-makers
that, “if democracy is fragile, then semi-presidentialism of any form is
probably best avoided.”
Steven Fish
takes, in his statistical analysis of twenty five post-communist
countries, a somewhat different approach. He does not deal with
semi-presidentialism per se, but instead measures the relative power of
parliament, on the hand, and the success of democratization, on the
other. Fish finds a surprisingly clear causal relationship between them.
The amount of prerogatives of a post-communist country’s legislature,
as determined by its Constitution, has a noticeable effect on the
democratic quality of that country’s political regime. Initially, there
had been no relevant correlation between the quality of democracy and
division of power, at the moment at which the various countries adopted
their Constitutions, in the 1990s. However, a few years later, in the
new century, those countries that had established relatively strong
legislatures were significantly more democratic than those with
relatively weak legislatures.
On that
basis, Fish comes to an even more explicit judgment than Elgie and
Moestrup concerning the various transition states in Central and Eastern
Europe and on the territory of the former Soviet Union. He concludes:
“The evidence shows that the presence of a powerful legislature is an unmixed blessing for democratization” (emphasis in the original). Concerning
the depth of the relationship between the strength of legislatures and
the extent of democratization, Fish writes: “The correlation is very
high. The strength of the national legislature may be a — or even the —
institutional key to democratization.” He advises: “The practical
implications of these findings are obvious. Would-be democratizers
should focus on creating a powerful legislature. In polities with weak
legislatures, democrats should make constitutional reforms to strengthen
the legislature a top priority.”
It
should be reminded that both Elgie’s & Moestrup’s, and Fish’s
findings are based on empirical research, i.e. on real-world
experiences. Much of what one hears in contemporary Ukrainian public
debates, instead, is based on fuzzy political suppositions, odd
cross-cultural comparison (for instance, with the US), or bold
counter-factual conjectures. Worse, sometimes this or that
constitutional arrangement is defended on the basis of historical
speculation or metaphysical rumination.
Against
the background of these findings, the key question in the next weeks
will be: Do Ukraine’s rulers actually want democratization to succeed,
and are they ready to seriously commit to this aim? Or will they try to
promote an alternative agenda focusing on economic recovery, political
stability, and administrative reform? President Yanukovych’s behavior
during the Orange Revolution in 2004 as well as recent actions by his
government and Party of Regions point to the latter rather than former
outlook. The problem with this approach is, of course, that democracy is
a crucial prerequisite for sustainable political stability, rational
economic planning, and effective public administration. Contrary to a
widely held belief in the post-Soviet world, parliamentary democracies
provide the head of the executive with more power than semi-presidential
systems which divide and thus diffuse governmental prerogatives.
In
the Ukrainian case, moreover, the consolidation of democracy is doubly
relevant to the future of this young nation-state. It will not only
provide a conflict-solving mechanism between the country’s rapacious
economic elites as well as between the culturally distinct populations
of the country’s west and center, on the one side, and south and east,
on the other. Democratization is also key to the long-term international
prospects of Ukraine, namely to the question of her EU membership
perspective. The idea of European integration and the aim to enter one
day the EU constitutes an important unifying idea that provides a common
denominator for the otherwise deeply divided political camps and social
groups of the west and east. All this suggests that the establishment
of either a parliament-dominated semi-presidential system, or even of a
purely parliamentary republic would constitute an important step towards
Ukraine’s future political development and integration into the
international community of democratic states.
Comments